DOI QR코드

DOI QR Code

Is Expansionary Fiscal and Monetary Policy Effective in Australia?

  • HSING, Yu (Department of Management & Business Administration, College of Business, Southeastern Louisiana University)
  • Received : 2019.04.30
  • Accepted : 2019.07.05
  • Published : 2019.07.30

Abstract

Purpose - This paper examines whether fiscal and monetary expansion would affect output in Australia. Research design, data, and methodology - An extended IS-LM model which describes the equilibrium in the goods market and the money market is applied. The real effective exchange rate and the real stock price are included in order to determine whether there may be any substitution or wealth effect. The sample consists of Annual data ranging from 1990 to 2018. The GARCH process is used in empirical work to correct for potential autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity. Results - Expansionary fiscal policy reduces output; whereas, expansionary monetary policy raises output. In addition, real appreciation of the Australian dollar, a lower U.S. interest rate, a higher real stock price or a lower expected inflation would increase output. The finding that expansionary fiscal policy has a negative impact on real GDP suggests that the negative crowding-out effect on private spending dominates the positive impact. Conclusions - Fiscal prudence needs to be pursued. Real depreciation of the Australian dollar hurts output. Monetary tightening in the U.S. generates a negative effect on Australia's output. A healthy stock market is conducive to economic growth as higher stock prices tend to result in the wealth and other positive effects, increasing consumption and business spending.

Keywords

1. Introduction

The Australian government has engaged in expansionary fiscal and monetary policy to stimulate the economy. During the recent global financial crisis, the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) increased real broad money by 15.72% in 2007 and 9.72% in 2008 in order to provide more liquidity and credit. Mainly due to the decrease in the policy rate, the lending rate also dropped from a high of 8.91% in 2008 to 6.92% in 2009 in order to reduce the cost of borrowing by consumers and businesses. At the same time, fiscal expansion was pursued. The government net borrowing-toGDP ratio rose from a low of -1.131% 2008 to a high of - 4.811% in 2010.

This paper examines whether fiscal and monetary expansion would affect Australia’s output and has several different aspects. First, this paper employs an extended ISLM model, which describes the equilibrium in the goods market and the money market. In the money demand function, the real effective exchange rate and the real stock price are included in order to determine whether there may be any substitution or wealth effect. Second, a theoretical model is developed to discuss potential impacts of expansionary fiscal and monetary policy on equilibrium output. Third, an advanced econometric methodology is employed in empirical work so that potential residual problems can be solved.

2. Literature Survey

Applying the IS-LM-Phillips curve model, Gali (1992) used money supply, money demand, IS and supply shocks to explain changes in output, prices, interest rates and money in the U.S. Supply shocks contributed to a large proportion of output fluctuations in the short run. The results matched well with the predictions of the IS-LM model.

Employing the SVAR model, Moreno (1992) examined macroeconomic shocks and business cycles in Australia and showed several major findings. Demand shocks raised aggregate output temporarily and prices permanently. Supply shocks played the more important role in the longer run. Technology shocks dominated supply shocks, raised aggregate output, and reduced prices. Shocks to crude oil prices and the supply of labor played smaller roles.

De Brouwer and O'Regan (1997) examined issues in applying monetary policy rules in Australia. A monetary rule was more useful if an inflation target is incorporated explicitly. A feedback rule with the output gap significantly reduced inflation volatility. Incorporation of the current and future information on inflation and output would improve the efficiency of the rule. De Brouwer and Gilbert (2005) analyzed the monetary policy reaction function in Australia and made several comments. The Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) had not tied to a single simple rule after the post-floating period because it has experienced three different monetary policy operating regimes. The RBA had raised the real cash rate in response to a higher inflation rate. [The monetary policy reaction function based on inflation and output may be over-simplified because the RBA also responded to changes in the U.S. monetary policy and depreciation of the trade-weighted exchange rate if the inflation rate is greater than 2.5%. The simple monetary policy reaction function implied a neutral interest rate between 5% and 5.5%.

Huh (1999) applied the IS-LM model to study Australia’s economy using five variables – IS, money demand, money supply, the world interest rate, and aggregate supply. His results were consistent with the predictions of the MundellFleming model. Expansionary monetary policy resulted in a permanent depreciation and a temporary increase in output. An increase in IS or money demand led to appreciation; whereas, a higher world interest rate resulted in depreciation.

Brischetto and Voss (1999) investigated the effects of monetary policy in Australia based on an extended model employed by Kim and Roubini (1999). They showed that monetary policy had a graduate and delayed impact on the general price level and a small transitory impact on aggregate output and that monetary policy reduced fluctuations in aggregate output and the general price level.

Perotti (2005) studied the effects of fiscal policy on output and several other macroeconomic variables for five OECD countries including Australia. The fiscal multiplier tended to be small. Only the government spending multiplier in the U.S. during the pre-1980 period was greater than one. There was a lack of evidence that tax cuts were more effective than government spending increase or that the tax multiplier was greater than the government spending multiplier. The effects of fiscal expansion, including more government spending or a tax cut, became significantly weaker and were negative in most cases during the post1980 period. There was evidence of a positive impact of government spending on long-term interest rates during the post-1980 period.

Ilzetzki, Mendoza, and Végh (2010) revealed that the effect of fiscal expansion depends on the exchange rate regime, government debt, trade openness, and the development stage based on a sample of 44 countries including Australia. The fiscal multiplier was zero under a floating exchange rate but relatively large under a predetermined exchange rate. The fiscal multiplier was negative in countries with a high level of debt. The fiscal multiplier was greater in closed economies than in open economies. The effect of fiscal expansion was greater in industrialized countries than in developing countries.

Furceri and Sousa (2011) analyzed the effects of government spending on private spending using a sample consisting of 145 countries, including Australia, during 1960- 2007. They found that government spending crowded out consumption and investment spending and that the effects did not change much during the phase of a business cycle but differed significantly among geographical regions.

Using a sample of 61 countries, including Australia, and using the panel data technique, including the fixed effect and the random effect, Karras (2011) found that the estimated long-run fiscal multiplier ranged from 1.21 to 1.53 in the full sample, from 1.44 to 2.43 for countries with fixed exchange rates, and from 0.98 to 1.39 for countries with floating exchange rates. Hence, fiscal multipliers were more effective under fixed exchange rates than under floating exchange rates. Based on a sample of 179 developing and developed countries, including Australia, during 1970-2011, Karras (2014) also showed that the domestic multiplier was much higher in the least open economies than in the most open economies, and that the spillover effect is much greater in the most open economies than in the least open economies. These results suggested that there would be a tradeoff of the domestic multiplier and the spillover effect in the least open and most open economies.

Blanchard, Ostry, Ghosh, and Chamon (2016, 2017) applied an extended Mundell-Fleming model to study the impacts of capital inflows on 19 emerging markets, including six Asian countries. They showed that bond inflows were contractionary due to currency appreciation; whereas, nonbond inflows also caused currency appreciation but reduce borrowing cost and were expansionary. Different policy tools needed to be used in combination in response to different types of inflows.

3. The Model

Suppose that aggregate expenditures are determined by real income, government tax revenues, government spending, the real interest rate, the real effective exchange rate, and the real stock price and that the demand for money is affected by the nominal interest rate, real income, the real stock price, the real effective exchange rate, and the world interest rate. Extending Romer (2006), we can express the IS and LM functions as:

\(Y=F(Y, T, G, R, \varepsilon, S)\)       (1)

\(M=L\left(R+\pi^{e}, Y, S, \varepsilon, R^{*}\right)\)       (2)

where

Y = real GDP or income,

T = government tax revenue,

G = government spending,

R = the real interest rate,

ε = the real effective exchange rate (An increase means real appreciation of the Australian dollar against other currencies.)

S = the real stock price,

M = real money supply,

Πe = the expected inflation rate, and ܴ

R* = the world interest rate.

The sign of the real stock price in the money demand function is unclear because there may be a substitution effect and a wealth effect of the real stock price on real money demand (Friedman, 1988; Thornton, 1998). When the real stock price rises, real money balances become less attractive, and people tend to substitute stocks for real money balances. On the other hand, when real stock prices increase, real wealth rises as well, which would increase real money demand for transaction, precautionary and speculative purposes.

The sign of the real effective exchange rate in the money demand function is unclear because there may be a substitution effect and a wealth effect between real money demand and the real effective exchange rate (Arango & Nadiri, 1981; Jamal & Hsing, 2011). As the Australian dollar appreciates versus other currencies, people may substitute the Australian dollar for other currencies in order to reduce the cost of exchange for the Australian dollar or engage in currency trading to make a profit in the future. On the other hand, people tend to maintain a desired level of wealth, including real money balances relative to other currencies. When the Australian dollar appreciates, people tend to reduce real money balances in order to maintain a desired level of wealth.

Solving for Y and ܴR simultaneously, we derive equilibrium real GDP as:

\(\bar{Y}=\bar{Y}\left(G-T, M, \varepsilon, R^{*}, S, \pi^{e}\right)\)       (3)

The Jacobian for the three endogenous variables can be written as:

\(|J|=\left[-L_{R}\left(1-F_{Y}\right)-F_{R} L_{Y}\right]>0\)       (4)

The effect of government budget deficit on equilibrium real GDP can be expressed as:

\(\partial \bar{Y} / \partial(G-T)=\left[-\left(F_{G}-F_{T}\right) L_{R}\right] / U \mid>0\)       (5)

The impact of real money supply on equilibrium real GDP is given by

\(\partial \bar{Y} / \partial M=-F_{R} / U \mid>0\)       (6)

The partial derivative of equilibrium real GDP with respect to the real effective exchange rate is given by:

\(\partial \bar{Y} / \partial \varepsilon=\left[-F_{\varepsilon} L_{R}+F_{R} L_{\varepsilon}\right] / U \mid<0 \text { or }>0.\)       (7)

The effect of the real stock price on equilibrium real GDP can be written as:

\(\partial \bar{Y} / \partial S=\left(-F_{S} L_{R}+F_{R} L_{S}\right) / U \mid<0 \text { or }>0.\)       (8)

These analyses suggest that expansionary fiscal policy is expected to raise equilibrium real GDP, that expansionary monetary policy is expected to increase equilibrium real GDP, that the effect of real appreciation of the Australian dollar on equilibrium real GDP depends on the sign of Lε, and that the impact of a higher real stock price on equilibrium real GDP is unclear depending upon the sign of LS. Although ߲ܻ\(\partial \bar{Y} / \partial(G-T)>0\), the sign may be zero or even negative due to the crowding-out effect, which indicates that positive effect of government deficit- or debtfinanced spending tends to be cancelled out by the negative effect of reduced consumption and investment spending.

4. Empirical Results

The data were collected from the Reserve Bank of Australia and the International Financial Statistics, which is published by the International Monetary Fund. Real GDP is measured in billions. The government deficit is expressed as a percent of GDP. Fiscal policy is represented by the government borrowing-to-GDP ratio. Real broad money is measured in billions. The world interest rate is represented by the U.S. government bond yield. The nominal stock price index is divided by the consumer price index to derive the real stock price. The expected inflation rate is the average inflation rate of the past three years. Real GDP, real broad money, the real stock price and the real oil price are expressed on a log scale. Other variables are measured in level due to possible negative values before or after log transformation. The sample consists of annual data ranging from 1990 to 2018. The quarterly data for government borrowing are not available.

The ADF test on the residual is applied to detect if there would be any cointegration among these time series variables. The value of the test statistic is estimated to be - 3.9495 as compared to the critical value of -3.5742. Hence, these variables are cointegrated and have a stable longterm relation.

Table 1 reports the estimated regression. The GARCH model is employed in empirical work to correct for autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity. Approximately 99.44% of the variation in real GDP can be explained by the six right-hand side variables. The coefficients of all the variables are significant at the 1% or 10% level. Real GDP has a positive relation with real broad money, real appreciation of the Australian dollar and the real stock price and a negative relation with the government borrowing-to-GDP ratio, the U.S. interest rate, and the expected inflation rate. The finding that expansionary fiscal policy has a negative impact on real GDP suggests that the negative crowding-out effect on private spending dominates the positive impact. The mean absolute percent error is estimated to be 1.7016%, suggesting that the forecast error is relatively small.

Table 1: Estimated Log(Real GDP) in Australia

OTGHDI_2019_v9n3_5_t0001.png 이미지

Specifically, a 1% increase in real broad money would raise real GDP by 0.4528%. If the U.S. interest rate rises 1 percentage point, the log of real GDP would decline by 0.0378. If the real stock price increases 1%, real GDP would increase by 0.0624%. When the expected inflation rate rises 1 percentage point, the log of real GDP declines by 0.0022.

5. Summary and Conclusions

This paper has examined whether expansionary fiscal and monetary policy would affect Australia’s output. Expansionary fiscal policy reduces real GDP; whereas, expansionary monetary policy raises real GDP. In addition, real appreciation of the Australian dollar, a lower U.S. interest rate, a higher real stock price or a lower expected inflation would raise real GDP.

There are several policy implications. Because expansionary fiscal policy has a negative impact on real GDP, fiscal prudence may need to be exercised. Monetary policy plays a more significant role. A healthy stock market is conducive to economic growth as higher stock prices tend to result in the wealth and other positive effects, increasing consumption and business spending.

Potential future research may apply the IS-MP-AS model (Romer, 2000, 2006) to examine the impacts of expansionary fiscal and monetary policies on real GDP. The advantage of this model is the incorporation of the monetary policy reaction function and inflation targeting to replace the LM function. Empirical results would determine which model would work better for Australia.

References

  1. Arango, S., & Nadiri, M. I. (1981). Demand for money in open economies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 7(1), 69-83. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(81)90052-0
  2. Blanchard, O., Ostry, J. D., Ghosh, A. R., & Chamon, M. (2016). Capital flows: expansionary or contractionary? American Economic Review, 106(5), 565-69. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20161012
  3. Blanchard, O., Ostry, J. D., Ghosh, A. R., & Chamon, M. (2017). Are capital inflows expansionary or contractionary? Theory, policy implications, and some evidence. IMF Economic Review, 65(3), 563-585. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-017-0039-z
  4. Brischetto, A., & Voss, G. (1999). A structural vector autoregression model of monetary policy in Australia. Sydney, Australia: Reserve Bank of Australia.
  5. Chen, Y., & Liu, D. (2018). Government spending shocks and the real exchange rate in China: Evidence from a sign-restricted VAR model. Economic Modelling, 68(1), 543-554. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2017.03.027
  6. Choudhry, T. (1996). Real stock prices and the long-run money demand function: evidence from Canada and the USA. Journal of International Money and Finance, 15(1), 1-17. https://doi.org/10.1016/0261-5606(95)00041-0
  7. De Brouwer, G., & O'Regan, J. (1997). Evaluating simple monetary policy rules for Australia. Canberra, Australia: The Australian National University.
  8. De Brouwer, G., & Gilbert, J. (2005). Monetary policy reaction functions in Australia. Economic Record, 81(253), 124-134. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-4932.2005.00238.x
  9. Dornbusch, R. (1976). Expectations and exchange rate dynamics. Journal of Political Economy, 84(6), 1161-1176. https://doi.org/10.1086/260506
  10. Fleming, J. M. (1962). Domestic financial policies under fixed and under floating exchange rates. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 9(3), 369-379 https://doi.org/10.2307/3866091
  11. Friedman, M. (1988). Money and the stock market. Journal of Political Economy, 96(2), 221-245. https://doi.org/10.1086/261534
  12. Furceri, D., & Sousa, R. M. (2011). The impact of government spending on the private sector: Crowding-out versus crowding-in effects. Kyklos, 64(4), 516-533 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6435.2011.00518.x
  13. Gali, J. (1992). How well does the IS-LM model fit postwar US data? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 709-738. https://doi.org/10.2307/2118487
  14. Huh, H. S. (1999). How well does the Mundell-Fleming model fit Australian data since the collapse of Bretton Woods? Applied Economics, 31(3), 397-407. https://doi.org/10.1080/000368499324372
  15. Jamal, A. M. M., & Hsing, Y. (2011). The demand for money in a simultaneous-equation framework. Economics Bulletin, 31(2), 1929-1934.
  16. Jeong, M., Kang, J., & Kim, S. (2017). Effects of government spending shocks in China, Japan, and Korea. China Economic Journal, 10(2), 194-225. https://doi.org/10.1080/17538963.2017.1321880
  17. Karras, G. (2011). Exchange-rate regimes and the effectiveness of fiscal policy. Journal of Economic Integration, 26(1), 29-44. https://doi.org/10.11130/jei.2011.26.1.29
  18. Karras, G. (2014). Fiscal policy spillovers through trade openness. Journal of Economic Integration, 29(3), 563-581. https://doi.org/10.11130/jei.2014.29.3.563
  19. Kim, S., & Roubini, N. (1999). Exchange rate anomalies in the industrial countries: A solution with a structural VAR approach. University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign, mimeo.
  20. Mankiw, N. G. (2019). Macroeconomics (10th ed.). New York, NY: Worth Publishers.
  21. Moreno, R. (1992). Macroeconomic shocks and business cycles in Australia. Economic Review-Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 3, 34.
  22. Mundell, R. A. (1963). Capital mobility and stabilization policy under fixed and flexible exchange rates. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 29(4), 475-485 https://doi.org/10.2307/139336
  23. Mundell, R. (2001). On the history of the Mundell-Fleming model. Keynote speech. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, Special Issue, 47(November), 215-232.
  24. Obstfeld, M. (2001). International macroeconomics: Beyond the Mundell-Fleming model. International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, Special Issue, 47(November), 1-39
  25. Perotti, R. (2005). Estimating the effects of fiscal policy in OECD countries (Working Paper No. 276). Milan, Italy: University of Bocconi.
  26. Romer, D. (2000). Keynesian macroeconomics without the LM curve. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(2), 149-169. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.14.2.149
  27. Romer, D. (2006). Advanced Macroeconomics. Boston, MA: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
  28. Siklos, P. L. (1988). The deficit-interest rate link: empirical evidence for Canada. Applied Economics, 20(12), 1563-1577. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036848800000088
  29. Thornton, J. (1998). Real stock prices and the long-run demand for money in Germany. Applied Financial Economics, 8(5), 513-517. https://doi.org/10.1080/096031098332817
  30. Weeks, J. (2009). The effectiveness of monetary policy reconsidered (PERI Working Papers No. 154).

Cited by

  1. Applying AHP in Evaluation the Distribution Science of Suppliers for Retails in Vietnam: Case of Saigon Co-op Mart vol.19, pp.3, 2019, https://doi.org/10.15722/jds.19.3.202103.35